(Related to the Apply the Concept on page 346) In 2012 , the San Francisco Giants Major League Baseball team signed pitcher Matt Cain to a contract that paid him a salary of \(\$ 20\) million per year from 2013 through 2017 . The annual salaries were all guaranteed, and the Giants had to pay Cain whether he performed well or not \(-\) and they had to pay him even if the team released him and he no longer played for the Giants. During \(2016,\) Cain pitched ineffectively, and at the beginning of the 2017 season, it was uncertain whether the Giants would keep him as a regular player. Giants General Manager Bobby Evans was quoted as saying that in the decision on Cain, his salary wasn't a factor: "It's really not about the money at this point." Is Evans's analysis correct? Should the salary the Giants are paying Cain matter in deciding whether to keep him on the team? Would the team's decision be affected if Cain were receiving the Major League Baseball minimum salary of \(\$ 535,000 ?\) Briefly explain.

Short Answer

Expert verified
Evans's analysis is correct from an economic perspective. Sunk costs, like Cain's salary, should not affect future decisions like keeping him on the team. However, practical considerations may come into play in a real-world scenario.

Step by step solution

01

Understand the Contract

Matt Cain was signed by the Giants in 2012 with a contract that paid him a salary of $20 million per year from 2013 to 2017. Even if the performance is not satisfactory, the team is obliged to pay the salary.
02

Sunk Cost

The salary of $20 million that the Giants have to pay Cain, regardless of his performance or whether he remains in the team, is a sunk cost. Sunk costs are costs that have already been incurred and cannot be recovered or changed.
03

Evaluate the Statement by Evans

As Cain's salary is a sunk cost, it does not factor into the decision about whether to keep him on the team. The decision should be based on Cain's projected future performance and the potential benefit to the team. Thus, Evans's statement that Cain's salary doesn't affect the decision is correct in terms of basic economic principles.
04

Consider Impact of Different Salary

If Cain were receiving a lower salary (such as the Major League Baseball minimum salary of $535,000), this would not change the fact that it is sunk cost. However, it may have practical implications on the organization's budget and financial planning. Yet, in economic perspective, it should not affect the decision to keep him on the team unless there are budget constraints.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Understanding Sunk Costs in Economic Decision-Making
When it comes to making economic decisions, it's crucial to distinguish between costs that are relevant and those that are not. A common mistake is to let sunk costs influence decision-making. Sunk costs are expenses that have been incurred in the past and cannot be recovered—money spent that is gone for good. In the context of the baseball team and Matt Cain's contract, the Giants' obligation to pay him $20 million annually from 2013 to 2017 represents a sunk cost.

When Bobby Evans, the Giants' General Manager, states that Cain's salary isn't a factor, he's adhering to the key principle that only future costs and benefits should influence the decision. This approach is rational; it avoids the 'sunk cost fallacy,' a common cognitive bias where individuals continue a behavior or endeavor based on previously invested resources (time, money, or effort).

Imagine a scenario where a baseball team is considering the roster for the upcoming season. Should they consider the salary already promised to a player who is underperforming? From an economic standpoint, the answer is no. The team should focus on what that player could contribute in the future and whether they are the best option available. Allocating a slot to a less effective player simply because of past financial commitments represents an opportunity cost, which is the potential benefit lost when one alternative is chosen over another.

It's worth noting that while sunk costs should not affect decisions, sometimes psychological and public relations factors may come into play—especially in high-profile settings like professional sports.
Contractual Obligations in Sports
Contractual obligations are a critical aspect of professional sports, affecting both financial planning and team strategy. Take the case of the Giants and Matt Cain: the terms of Cain's contract are binding, meaning the team is legally required to pay the agreed-upon salary, regardless of his performance level or whether he still plays for the team.

In sports economics, contracts are often structured to provide financial security for players, while teams must manage the implications of these contracts on their budgets and rosters. The fact that Cain's salary is a sunk cost does not negate the Giants' obligation to pay it. What the team must consider is how to assemble the best possible roster within their budget constraints while upholding contractual commitments.

It is interesting to ponder how enduring these obligations influence roster decisions in the long term. Teams often must balance the need to honor contracts with the goal of fielding competitive players. In Cain's situation, if the Giants decided to release him, they would still have to pay him—even as they search for a replacement. This financial strain must be weighed against the potential on-field performance gains from moving on. While sunk costs should not theoretically influence the decision, broader strategic and financial planning invariably come into play.
Performance Evaluation in Economics
Performance evaluation is a pivotal concept in economics, particularly when it involves sizing up investments and determining their future value. In the case of Matt Cain and the San Francisco Giants, evaluating whether to keep Cain as a regular player hinges on assessing his anticipated future performance.

An effective economic evaluation will consider factors such as the player's health, recent performance trends, skills compared to alternatives, and the overall strategy of the team. This is where performance evaluation intersects with economic decision-making: should the investment in Cain's salary be maintained for potential future returns in the form of wins and performance on the field?

While the Giants’ contractual obligations to Cain are fixed, making the best use of their resources moving forward is about making decisions that maximize future gains. This may involve a complex analysis involving statistical forecasts, player development potential, and team dynamics. Economically, if Cain is expected to underperform compared to other players who may fill his spot for lower salaries, it could make sense to replace him despite the sunk cost of his contract.

The rigor of performance evaluation in economics lies not simply in quantifying past results but in forecasting future potential and making decisions that will lead to better overall outcomes for the organization. It’s not just about data—it’s about interpretation, strategy, and smart economic planning.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Considering only the income effect, if the price of an inferior good declines, would a consumer want to buy a larger quantity or a smaller quantity of the good? Does your answer mean that the demand curves for inferior goods should slope upward? Briefly explain.

Shawn Van Dyke, a construction industry consultant, wrote on a home building site: Brains do some pretty funny things when making a buying decision. If you understand your customers' brain activities, then you can use this knowledge to help increase your sales and deliver on value. \(\ldots\) There's an old question in advertising. "How do you sell a \(\$ 2,000\) watch? Put it next to a \(\$ 10,000\) watch." This is an example of price anchoring. a. What is price anchoring? b. Explain why Van Dyke cited the "old advertising question" as an example of price anchoring.

How is the market demand curve derived from consumers' individual demand curves?

Andrea grew up enjoying her Italian grandmother's homecooked meals. Chicken and pasta with meatballs were her favorite foods. But after Andrea graduated from college, found a job, and got married, she became a vegetarian and no longer ate chicken or meatballs. Briefly explain which of the following statements provides the most likely explanation of Andrea's decision to become a vegetarian: \(\bullet\) When Andrea was young, she was unrealistic about her future behavior. Therefore, she did not act rationally. \(\bullet\) Andrea was not working when she was young. After she graduated from college and became employed, her income rose. We can conclude that for Andrea, chicken, meatballs, and other meat products are inferior goods. \(\bullet\) Social influences explain Andrea's decision to become a vegetarian. More people, including celebrities from the entertainment field, have become vegetarians. Andrea became a vegetarian because she now feels a kinship with these celebrities, and being a vegetarian makes her appear to be fashionable.

Richard Thaler, winner of the 2017 Nobel Prize in Economics, was first to use the term endowment effect to describe placing a higher value on something already owned than would be placed on the object if not currently owned. According to an article in the Economist: Dr. Thaler, who recently had some expensive bottles of wine stolen, observes that he is "now confronted with precisely one of my own experiments: these are bottles I wasn't planning to sell and now I'm going to get a cheque from an insurance company and most of these bottles I will not buy. I'm a good enough economist to know there's a bit of an inconsistency there." Based on Thaler's statement, how do his stolen bottles of wine illustrate the endowment effect? Why did he make the statement: "I'm a good enough economist to know there's a bit of an inconsistency there"?

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free