An enterprising entrepreneur purchases two factories to produce widgets. Each factory produces identical products, and each has a production function given by \\[ q=\sqrt{k_{i} l_{i}}, \quad i=1,2 \\] The factories differ, however, in the amount of capital equipment each has, In particular, factory 1 has \(k_{1}=25,\) whereas factory 2 has \(k_{2}=100 .\) Rental rates for \(k\) and \(l\) are given by \(w=v=\$ 1\) a. If the entrepreneur wishes to minimize short-run total costs of widget production, how should output be allocated between the two factories? b. Given that output is optimally allocated between the two factories, calculate the short-run total, average, and marginal cost curves. What is the marginal cost of the 100 th widget? The 125 th widget? The 200 th widget? c. How should the entrepreneur allocate widget production between the two factories in the long run? Calculate the long-run total, average, and marginal cost curves for widget production. d. How would your answer to part (c) change if both factories exhibited diminishing returns to scale?

Short Answer

Expert verified
In summary, the optimal allocation of output between the two factories in the short-run is given by \(q_1 = \frac{Q}{3}\) and \(q_2 = \frac{2Q}{3}\). The short-run and long-run total, average, and marginal cost curves for the constant returns to scale scenario are: \[C(Q) = \frac{Q^2}{75} + 125\] \[AC(Q) = \frac{Q}{75} + \frac{125}{Q}\] \[MC(Q) = \frac{2Q}{75}\] The marginal costs of the 100th, 125th, and 200th widgets are approximately $26.67, $16.67, and $26.67, respectively. In the long run, the entrepreneur can adjust both k and l, and the allocation remains the same as in the short run. If both factories exhibit diminishing returns to scale, the entrepreneur needs to reconsider the allocation between the two factories in the long run, and the total, average, and marginal cost curves will also change.

Step by step solution

01

We are given the production function \[q=\sqrt{k_i l_i}, \quad i=1,2\] The rental rates for k and l are given by \(w=v=\$1\). Then, the costs of inputs are equal, and we can write the cost function for each factory as: \[C_i = w\cdot l_i + v\cdot k_i\] We need to minimize costs, considering the production function constraints. To do this, we can substitute the production function into the cost function for each factory: \[C_i = w\left(\frac{q_i^2}{k_i}\right) + vk_i\] For factory 1, with \(k_1 = 25\), we have: \[C_1 = \frac{q_1^2}{25}+25\] Similarly, for factory 2, with \(k_2 = 100\), we have: \[C_2 = \frac{q_2^2}{100}+100\] The entrepreneur wants to minimize the total cost \(C = C_1 + C_2\) while producing a total output \(Q = q_1 + q_2\). To minimize the total cost function subject to the constraint \(Q = q_1 + q_2\), we can use the Lagrange multipliers method. This gives us the following problem: Minimize: \(\mathcal {L} = C_1+ C_2 - (\lambda)[Q-(q_1+q_2)]\) Which yields the following first-order conditions: 1. \(\frac{\partial \mathcal {L}}{\partial q_1}=2*q_1/25 - \lambda = 0\) 2. \(\frac{\partial \mathcal {L}}{\partial q_2}=2*q_2/100 - \lambda = 0\) Now solve the system of equations to find \(q_1\) and \(q_2\): Divide equation (1) by 2 and equation (2) by 4: \(\frac{q_1}{25} - \frac{\lambda}{2} = 0\) and \(\frac{q_2}{100} - \frac{\lambda}{4} = 0\) Solving for \(\lambda\), we get: \(\lambda = \frac{2q_1}{25} = \frac{q_2}{50}\). From the constraint, we also have \(q_1 = Q-q_2\). Thus, \[Q - q_2 = \frac{25q_2}{50}\] Now, we have found that the optimal allocation of output between the two factories will be: \(q_1 = \frac{Q}{3}\) and \(q_2 = \frac{2Q}{3}\) #b. Short-run Total, Average, and Marginal Costs

First, use the optimal output allocation to find the total cost function: \[C(Q) = C_1+ C_2 = \frac{(\frac{Q}{3})^2}{25}+25+\frac{(\frac{2Q}{3})^2}{100}+100\] \[C(Q) = \frac{Q^2}{75}+125\] Now calculate the average cost and marginal cost functions: \[AC(Q) = \frac{C(Q)}{Q}=\frac{Q}{75}+\frac{125}{Q}\] \[MC(Q) = \frac{dC(Q)}{dQ}=\frac{2Q}{75}\] Next, we need to find the marginal costs of the 100th, 125th, and 200th widgets: \[MC(100) = \frac{2*100}{75} = \frac{80}{3}\approx26.67\] \[MC(125) = \frac{2*125}{75}=\frac{50}{3}\approx16.67\] \[MC(200) = \frac{2*200}{75}= \frac{80}{3} \approx 26.67 \] #C. Long-run Allocation and Costs
02

In the long run, the entrepreneur can adjust both k and l to minimize costs. Such optimization will result in equal marginal costs in both plants, as they produce identical products. In this scenario, the long-run allocation will be the same as in the short run, \(q_1 = \frac{Q}{3}\) and \(q_2 = \frac{2Q}{3}\). The long-run total, average, and marginal cost curves remain the same as those calculated for the short run: \[C(Q) = \frac{Q^2}{75}+125\] \[AC(Q) =\frac{Q}{75}+\frac{125}{Q}\] \[MC(Q) =\frac{2Q}{75}\] #d. Diminishing Returns to Scale

If both factories exhibited diminishing returns to scale, then the production function would change, meaning an increase in k and l would lead to a less-than-proportional increase in q. In this case, the entrepreneur needs to reconsider the allocation between the two factories in the long run to achieve cost minimization, and it might not be optimal to allocate the output in the same ratio as found in the short run. The new optimal allocation would depend on the specific production functions exhibiting diminishing returns to scale. However, the calculated total, average, and marginal cost curves would be different from those obtained for constant returns to scale. They would still be derived similarly by using the respective (new) production functions, but the actual numbers will change.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

The own-price elasticities of contingent input demand for labor and capital are defined as \\[ e_{Y},_{w}=\frac{\partial l^{c}}{\partial w} \cdot \frac{w}{l^{c}}, \quad e_{k^{\prime}, v}=\frac{\partial k^{c}}{\partial v} \cdot \frac{v}{k^{\ell}} \\] a. Calculate \(e_{\mathbb{R}, \text { w }}\) and \(e_{k_{k}, v}\) for each of the cost functions shown in Example 10.2 b. Show that, in general, \(c_{r}, w+e_{L r, v}=0\) c. Show that the cross-price derivatives of contingent demand functions are equal-that is, show that \(\partial f / \partial v=\partial k^{c} / \partial w\). Use this fact to show that \(s_{1} e_{\gamma, v}=s_{k} e_{k^{\prime}}, w\) where \(s_{b} s_{k}\) are, respectively, the share of labor in total cost \((w l / C)\) and of capital in total cost \((v k / C)\) d. Use the results from parts (b) and (c) to show that \(s_{i} €_{l^{\prime}, s, s}+s_{k} c_{k^{\prime}, w}=0\) e. Interpret these various elasticity relationships in words and discuss their overall relevance to a general theory of input demand.

Suppose the total-cost function for a firm is given by \\[ C=q w^{2 / 3} v^{1 / 3} \\] a. Use Shephard's lemma to compute the (constant output) demand functions for inputs \(l\) and \(k\). b. Use your results from part (a) to calculate the underlying production function for \(q\)

Professor Smith and Professor Jones are going to produce a new introductory textbook. As true scientists, they have laid out the production function for the book as \\[ q=S^{1 / 2} J^{1 / 2} \\] where \(q=\) the number of pages in the finished book, \(S=\) the number of working hours spent by Smith, and \(J=\) the number of hours spent working by Jones. After having spent 900 hours preparing the first draft, time which he valued at \(\$ 3\) per working hour, Smith has to move on to other things and cannot contribute any more to the book. Jones, whose labor is valued at \(\$ 12\) per working hour, will revise Smith's draft to complete the book. a. How many hours will Jones have to spend to produce a finished book of 150 pages? Of 300 pages? Of 450 pages? b. What is the marginal cost of the 150 th page of the finished book? Of the 300 th page? Of the 450 th page?

Suppose that a firm's fixed proportion production function is given by \\[ q=\min (5 k, 10 l) \\] a. Calculate the firm's long-run total, average, and marginal cost functions. b. Suppose that \(k\) is fixed at 10 in the short run. Calculate the firm's short-run total, average, and marginal cost functions. c. Suppose \(v=1\) and \(w=3 .\) Calculate this firm's long-run and short-run average and marginal cost curves.

Suppose the total-cost function for a firm is given by \\[ C=q(v+2 \sqrt{v w}+w) \\] a. Use Shephard's lemma to compute the (constant output) demand function for cach input, \(k\) and \(l\). b. Use the results from part (a) to compute the underlying production function for \(q\) c. You can check the result by using results from Fxample 10.2 to show that the CES cost function with \(\sigma=0.5, \rho=-1\) generates this total-cost function.

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free