Suppose there is a \(50-50\) chance that an individual with logarithmic utility from wealth and with a current wealth of \(\$ 20,000\) will suffer a loss of \(\$ 10,000\) from a car accident. Insurance is competitively provided at actuarially fair rates. a. Compute the outcome if the individual buys full insurance. b. Compute the outcome if the individual buys only partial insurance covering half the loss. Show that the outcome in part (a) is preferred. c. Now suppose that individuals who buy the partial rather than the full insurance policy take more carc when driving, reducing the damage from loss from \(\$ 10,000\) to \(\$ 7,000\). What would be the actuarially fair price of the partial policy? Does the individual now prefer the full or the partial policy?

Short Answer

Expert verified
The individual prefers to buy partial insurance and take more care when driving, as it results in a higher expected utility compared to full or partial insurance without taking extra care.

Step by step solution

01

Derive the utility function

The individual's utility function is written in logarithmic form, which means: \[u(W) = \ln(W)\] where \(W\) represents the wealth of the individual.
02

Calculate expected utilities for each scenario

For each scenario, the expected utility can be calculated as follows: \[E[u(W)] = p \cdot u(W_{1}) + (1-p) \cdot u(W_{2})\] where \(W_{1}\) and \(W_{2}\) are the individual's wealth after facing loss or no loss, respectively, and \(p\) is the probability of facing the loss. Let's calculate the expected utilities for each scenario:
03

a. Full insurance

In this case, the individual pays the actuarially fair premium to cover the entire loss. The premium is equal to the probability of the loss multiplied by the amount of the loss: \[Premium = p \cdot L = 0.5 \cdot \$ 10,000 = \$ 5,000\] When an accident occurs (probability 0.5): \[W_{1} = \$ 20,000 - \$ 10,000 + \$ 10,000 - \$ 5,000 = \$ 15,000\] When there is no accident (probability 0.5): \[W_{2} = \$ 20,000 - \$ 5,000 = \$ 15,000\] Expected utility: \[E[u(W)] = 0.5 \cdot \ln(\$ 15,000) + 0.5 \cdot \ln(\$ 15,000) = \ln(\$ 15,000)\]
04

b. Partial insurance

The individual pays a premium to cover half the loss: \[Premium = 0.5 \cdot L/2 = 0.5 \cdot \$ 5,000 = \$ 2,500\] When an accident occurs (probability 0.5): \[W_{1} = \$ 20,000 - \$ 10,000 + \$ 5,000 - \$ 2,500 = \$ 12,500\] When there is no accident (probability 0.5): \[W_{2} = \$ 20,000 - \$ 2,500 = \$ 17,500\] Expected utility: \[E[u(W)] = 0.5 \cdot \ln(\$ 12,500) + 0.5 \cdot \ln(\$ 17,500)\]
05

c. Partial insurance with more careful driving

The individual pays a premium to cover the reduced loss of \(L = \$ 7,000\): \[Premium = 0.5 \cdot L/2 = 0.5 \cdot \$ 3,500 = \$ 1,750\] When an accident occurs (probability 0.5): \[W_{1} = \$ 20,000 - \$ 7,000 + \$ 3,500 - \$ 1,750 = \$ 14,750\] When there is no accident (probability 0.5): \[W_{2} = \$ 20,000 - \$ 1,750 = \$ 18,250\] Expected utility: \[E[u(W)] = 0.5 \cdot \ln(\$ 14,750) + 0.5 \cdot \ln(\$ 18,250)\]
06

Compare expected utilities

Now, we will compare the expected utilities for all three scenarios: a. Full insurance: \(E[u(W)] = \ln(\$ 15,000)\) b. Partial insurance: \(E[u(W)] = 0.5 \cdot \ln(\$ 12,500) + 0.5 \cdot \ln(\$ 17,500)\) c. Partial insurance with more care: \(E[u(W)] = 0.5 \cdot \ln(\$ 14,750) + 0.5 \cdot \ln(\$ 18,250)\) We can observe that (by either calculating numerically or just observing the values of W): \(E[u(W)]_{a} > E[u(W)]_{b}\), implying the individual prefers full insurance over partial insurance. Next, we compare (a) and (c): \(E[u(W)]_{a} < E[u(W)]_{c}\), implying the individual prefers partial insurance with more careful driving over full insurance.
07

Conclusion

The individual prefers to buy partial insurance and take more care when driving, as it results in a higher expected utility compared to full or partial insurance without taking extra care.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose the agent can be one of three types rather than just two as in the chapter. a. Return to the monopolist's problem of computing the optimal nonlinear price. Represent the first best in a schematic diagram by modifying Figure \(18.4 .\) Do the same for the second best by modifying Figure 18.6 b. Return to the monopolist's problem of designing optimal insurance policies. Represent the first best in a schematic diagram by modifying Figure \(18.7 .\) Do the same for the second best by modifying Figure 18.8

Increasing the size of a team that creates a joint product may dull incentives, as this problem will illustrate. \(^{11}\) Suppose \(n\) partners together produce a revenue of \(R=e_{1}+\cdots+e_{n} ;\) here \(e_{i}\) is partner \(i\) s effort, which costs him \(c\left(e_{i}\right)=e_{i}^{2} / 2\) to exert. a. Compute the equilibrium effort and surplus (revenue minus effort cost) if each partner receives an equal share of the revenue. b. Compute the equilibrium effort and average surplus if only one partner gets a share. Is it better to concentrate the share or to disperse it? c. Return to part (a) and take the derivative of surplus per partner with respect to \(n\). Is surplus per partner increasing or decreasing in \(n ?\) What is the limit as \(n\) increases? d. Some commentators say that ESOPs (employee stock ownership plans, whereby part of the firm's shares are distributed among all its workers) are beneficial because they provide incentives for employees to work hard. What does your answer to part (c) say about the incentive properties of ESOPs for modern corporations, which may have thousands of workers?

Suppose that left-handed people are more prone to injury than right-handed people. Iefties have an 80 percent chance of suffering an injury leading to a \(\$ 1,000\) loss (in terms of medical expenses and the monetary equivalent of pain and suffering) but righties have only a 20 percent chance of suffering such an injury. The population contains equal numbers of lefties and rightics. Individuals all have logarithmic utility-of-wealth functions and initial wealth of \(\$ 10,000\). Insurance is provided by a monopoly company. a. Compute the first best for the monopoly insurer (i.e., supposing it can observe the individual's dominant hand). b. Take as given that, in the second best, the monopolist prefers not to serve rightics at all and targets only leftics. Knowing this, compute the second- best menu of policies for the monopoly insurer. c. Use a spreadsheet program (such as the one on the website associated with Example 18.5 ) or other mathematical software to solve numerically the constrained optimization problem for the second best. Make sure to add constraints bounding the insurance payments for righties: \(0 \leq x_{R} \leq 1,000\). Establish that the constraint \(0 \leq x_{R}\) is binding and so righties are not served in the second best.

A painting is auctioned to \(n\) bidders, each with a private value for the painting that is uniformly distributed between 0 and 1 a. Compute the equilibrium bidding strategy in a first-price sealed-bid auction. Compute the seller's expected revenue in this auction. Hint: Use the formula for the expected value of the \(k\) th-order statistic for uniform distributions in Equation 18.71 b. Compute the equilibrium bidding strategy in a second-price sealed-bid auction. Compute the seller's expected revenue in this auction using the hint from part (a). c. Do the two auction formats exhibit revenue equivalence? d. For each auction format, how do bidders' strategies and the seller's revenue change with an increase in the number of bidders?

Consider the principal-agent relationship between a patient and doctor. Suppose that the patient's utility function is given by \(U_{P}(m, x),\) where \(m\) denotes medical care (whose quantity is determined by the doctor) and \(x\) denotes other consumption goods. The patient faces budget constraint \(I_{c}=p_{m} m+x,\) where \(p_{m}\) is the relative price of medical care. The doctor's utility function is given by \(U_{d}\left(I_{d}\right)+U_{P}-\) that is, the doctor derives utility from income but, being altruistic, also derives utility from the patient's well-being. Moreover, the additive specification implies that the doctor is a perfect altruist in the sense that his or her utility increases one-for-one with the patient's. The doctor's income comes from the patient's medical expenditures: \(I_{d}=p_{m} m .\) Show that, in this situation, the doctor will generally choose a level of \(m\) that is higher than a fully informed patient would choose.

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free