Heidi receives utility from two goods, goat's milk ( \(m\) ) and strudel (s), according to the utility function \\[U(m, s)=m \cdot s.\\] a. Show that increases in the price of goat's milk will not affect the quantity of strudel Heidi buys; that is, show that \(\partial s / \partial p_{m}=0\). b. Show also that \(\partial m / \partial p_{s}=0\). c. Use the Slutsky equation and the symmetry of net substitution effects to prove that the income effects involved with the derivatives in parts (a) and (b) are identical. d. Prove part (c) explicitly using the Marshallian demand functions for \(m\) and \(s\).

Short Answer

Expert verified
In summary: a. We proved that the quantity of strudel Heidi buys is not affected by the price of goat's milk (\(\partial s / \partial p_{m} = 0\)). b. We also showed that the quantity of goat's milk Heidi buys is not affected by the price of strudel (\(\partial m / \partial p_{s} = 0\)). c. We used the Slutsky equation to prove that the income effects for goat's milk and strudel are identical. The key result being that the ratio (\(\frac{\partial s / \partial I}{\partial m / \partial I}\)) is equal to 1. d. Finally, we explicitly proved the same result in part (c) using the Marshallian demand functions for \(m\) and \(s\), confirming the identical income effects for both goods.

Step by step solution

01

a. Show that \(\partial s / \partial p_{m} = 0\).

We are given Heidi's utility function \\[U(m, s) = m \cdot s.\\] The expenditure for \(m\) and \(s\) are \(p_m \cdot m\) and \(p_s \cdot s\), respectively. Let's assume that Heidi's income is \(I\). Then her budget constraint can be written as \\[p_m \cdot m + p_s \cdot s = I.\\] To find the optimal consumption of \(m\) and \(s\), we need to maximize the utility function subject to the budget constraint. To do this, we can use the Lagrange method with the Lagrangian as follows: \\[\mathcal{L} = U(m, s) + \lambda (I - p_m \cdot m - p_s \cdot s).\\] Now we need to find the partial derivatives of the Lagrangian with respect to \(m\), \(s\), and \(\lambda\) and set them equal to zero: 1. \\[\frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial m} = s - \lambda p_m = 0.\\] 2. \\[\frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial s} = m - \lambda p_s = 0.\\] 3. \\[\frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial \lambda} = I - p_m \cdot m - p_s \cdot s = 0.\\] Now we need to solve these equations to find partial derivative \(\partial s / \partial p_{m}\): From equation (1), \\[\lambda = \frac{s}{p_m}.\\] From equation (2), \\[\lambda = \frac{m}{p_s}.\\] Combining both equations, we get \\[\frac{s}{p_m} = \frac{m}{p_s} \Rightarrow s = \frac{m p_m}{p_s}.\\] Now, let's find the partial derivative of \(s\) with respect to \(p_m\): \\[\frac{\partial s}{\partial p_{m}} = \frac{\partial}{\partial p_{m}} \left(\frac{m p_m}{p_s}\right) = \frac{m}{p_s}.\\] Since \(m\) and \(p_s\) are independent of \(p_m\), the partial derivative \(\partial s / \partial p_{m}\) is equal to zero. Hence, the quantity of strudel Heidi buys is not affected by the price of goat's milk.
02

b. Show that \(\partial m / \partial p_{s} = 0\).

Using the result from the previous part, we found that \(\lambda = \frac{s}{p_m} = \frac{m}{p_s}\). Now let's find the partial derivative of \(m\) with respect to \(p_s\): From the expression of \(\lambda\), we can rewrite it as: \\[m = \frac{s p_s}{p_m}.\\] Now, let's compute the partial derivative of \(m\) with respect to \(p_s\): \\[\frac{\partial m}{\partial p_{s}} = \frac{\partial}{\partial p_{s}} \left(\frac{s p_s}{p_m}\right) = \frac{s}{p_m}.\\] Since \(s\) and \(p_m\) are independent of \(p_s\), the partial derivative \(\partial m / \partial p_{s}\) is equal to zero. Hence, the quantity of goat's milk Heidi buys is not affected by the price of strudel.
03

c. Use the Slutsky equation to prove that the income effects are identical.

The Slutsky equation states that the total effect on the demand for a good due to a price change can be decomposed into a substitution effect and an income effect: \\[\frac{\partial x_i}{\partial p_j} = \frac{\partial h_i}{\partial p_j} - \frac{\delta_{ij} x_i}{\partial I}.\\] In our case, \(i\) and \(j\) can be either \(m\) or \(s\). We know from parts (a) and (b) that \(\frac{\partial s}{\partial p_m} = \frac{\partial m}{\partial p_{s}} = 0\) and the substitution effects are also zero because the utility function exhibits a constant marginal rate of substitution. Therefore, we are left with: \\[\frac{\partial s / \partial I}{\partial m / \partial I} = 1.\\] This equality implies that the income effects for both goods are identical.
04

d. Prove part (c) explicitly using the Marshallian demand functions for \(m\) and \(s\).

To prove part (c) explicitly, we need to find the Marshallian demand functions for \(m\) and \(s\) based on their respective expressions we derived earlier: \\[m = \frac{s p_s}{p_m},\\] \\[s = \frac{m p_m}{p_s}.\\] Using the budget constraint \(p_m \cdot m + p_s \cdot s = I\), we can substitute the expressions for \(m\) and \(s\) into the constraint equation: \\[p_m \cdot \frac{s p_s}{p_m} + p_s \cdot \frac{m p_m}{p_s} = I \Rightarrow s^2 + m^2 = \frac{I^2}{p_m^2 + p_s^2}.\\] Now, let's find the demand functions \(m(I, p_m, p_s)\) and \(s(I, p_m, p_s)\): 1. \\[m(I, p_m, p_s) = \frac{s(I, p_m, p_s) p_s}{p_m}.\\] 2. \\[s(I, p_m, p_s) = \frac{m(I, p_m, p_s) p_m}{p_s}.\\] Taking derivative of both the demand functions with respect to Income \(I\): 1. From part (a), we know that \(\frac{\partial s}{\partial p_m} = 0\). So, using the budget constraint, we find the derivative with respect to \(I\): \\[\frac{\partial m}{\partial I} = \frac{p_m}{p_m^2 + p_s^2}.\\] 2. Similarly, using the result from part (b) along with the budget constraint, we find the derivative with respect to \(I\): \\[\frac{\partial s}{\partial I} = \frac{p_s}{p_m^2 + p_s^2}.\\] The ratios of these income effects are: \\[\frac{\partial s / \partial I}{\partial m / \partial I} = \frac{\frac{p_s}{p_m^2 + p_s^2}}{\frac{p_m}{p_m^2 + p_s^2}} = \frac{p_s}{p_m} = 1.\\] Thus, we have proven explicitly that the income effects for goat's milk and strudel are identical.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Graphing complements is complicated because a complementary relationship between goods (under Hicks' definition) cannot occur with only two goods. Rather, complementarity necessarily involves the demand relationships among three (or more) goods. In his review of complementarity, Samuelson provides a way of illustrating the concept with a two-dimensional indifference curve diagram (see the Suggested Readings). To examine this construction, assume there are three goods that a consumer might choose. The quantities of these are denoted by \(x_{1}, x_{2},\) and \(x_{3} .\) Now proceed as follows. a. Draw an indifference curve for \(x_{2}\) and \(x_{3},\) holding the quantity of \(x_{1}\) constant at \(x_{1}^{0} .\) This indifference curve will have the customary convex shape. b. Now draw a second (higher) indifference curve for \(x_{2}, x_{3},\) holding \(x_{1}\) constant at \(x_{1}^{0}-h .\) For this new indifference curve, show the amount of extra \(x_{2}\) that would compensate this person for the loss of \(x_{1} ;\) call this amount \(j .\) Similarly, show that amount of extra \(x_{3}\) that would compensate for the loss of \(x_{1}\) and call this amount \(k\) c. Suppose now that an individual is given both amounts \(j\) and \(k\), thereby permitting him or her to move to an even higher \(x_{2}, x_{3}\) indifference curve. Show this move on your graph, and draw this new indifference curve. d. Samuelson now suggests the following definitions: If the new indifference curve corresponds to the indifference curve when \(x_{1}=x_{1}^{0}-2 h,\) goods 2 and 3 are independent. If the new indifference curve provides more utility than when \(x_{1}=x_{1}^{0}-2 h,\) goods 2 and 3 are complements. If the new indifference curve provides less utility than when \(x_{1}=x_{1}^{0}-2 h,\) goods 2 and 3 are substitutes. Show that these graphical definitions are symmetric. e. Discuss how these graphical definitions correspond to Hicks' more mathematical definitions given in the text. f. Looking at your final graph, do you think that this approach fully explains the types of relationships that might exist between \(x_{2}\) and \(x_{3} ?\)

Ms. Sarah Traveler does not own a car and travels only by bus, train, or plane. Her utility function is given by \\[\text { utility }=b \cdot t \cdot p,\\] where each letter stands for miles traveled by a specific mode. Suppose that the ratio of the price of train travel to that of bus travel \(\left(p_{t} / p_{b}\right)\) never changes a. How might one define a composite commodity for ground transportation? b. Phrase Sarah's optimization problem as one of choosing between ground \((g)\) and air \((p)\) transportation. c. What are Sarah's demand functions for \(g\) and \(p ?\) d. Once Sarah decides how much to spend on \(g\), how will she allocate those expenditures between \(b\) and \(t\) ?

Details of the analysis suggested in Problems 6.5 and 6.6 were originally worked out by Borcherding and Silberberg (see the Suggested Readings) based on a supposition first proposed by Alchian and Allen. These authors look at how a transaction charge affects the relative demand for two closely substitutable items. Assume that goods \(x_{2}\) and \(x_{3}\) are close substitutes and are subject to a transaction charge of \(t\) per unit. Suppose also that good 2 is the more expensive of the two goods (i.e., "good apples" as opposed to "cooking apples". Hence the transaction charge lowers the relative price of the more expensive good [i.e., \(\left.\left(p_{2}+t\right) /\left(p_{3}+t\right) \text { decreases as } t \text { increases }\right] .\) This will increase the relative demand for the expensive good if \(\partial\left(x_{2}^{c} / x_{3}^{c}\right) / \partial t > 0\) (where we use compensated demand functions to eliminate pesky income effects). Borcherding and Silberberg show this result will probably hold using the following steps. a. Use the derivative of a quotient rule to expand \(\partial\left(x_{2}^{c} / x_{3}^{c}\right) / \partial t\). b. Use your result from part (a) together with the fact that, in this problem, \(\partial x_{i}^{\epsilon} / \partial t=\partial x_{i}^{c} / \partial p_{2}+\partial x_{i}^{\epsilon} / \partial p_{3}\) for \(i=2,3,\) to show that the derivative we seek can be written as \\[\frac{\partial\left(x_{2}^{c} / x_{3}^{c}\right)}{\partial t}=\frac{x_{2}^{c}}{x_{3}^{c}}\left[\frac{s_{22}}{x_{2}}+\frac{s_{23}}{x_{2}}-\frac{s_{32}}{x_{3}}-\frac{s_{33}}{x_{3}}\right],\\] \(\text { where } s_{i j}=\partial x_{i}^{c} / \partial p_{j}.\) c. Rewrite the result from part (b) in terms of compensated price elasticities: \\[e_{i j}^{c}=\frac{\partial x_{i}^{c}}{\partial p_{j}} \cdot \frac{p_{j}}{x_{i}^{c}},\\] d. Use Hicks' third law (Equation 6.26 ) to show that the term in brackets in parts (b) and (c) can now be written as \\[\left[\left(e_{22}-e_{23}\right)\left(1 / p_{2}-1 / p_{3}\right)+\left(e_{21}-e_{31}\right) / p_{3}\right].\\] e. Develop an intuitive argument about why the expression in part (d) is likely to be positive under the conditions of this problem. Hints: Why is the first product in the brackets positive? Why is the second term in brackets likely to be small? f. Return to Problem 6.6 and provide more complete explanations for these various findings.

Donald, a frugal graduate student, consumes only coffee ( \(c\) ) and buttered toast (bt). He buys these items at the university cafeteria and always uses two pats of butter for each piece of toast. Donald spends exactly half of his meager stipend on coffee and the other half on buttered toast. a. In this problem, buttered toast can be treated as a composite commodity. What is its price in terms of the prices of butter \(\left(p_{b}\right)\) and toast \(\left(p_{t}\right) ?\) b. Explain why \(\partial c / \partial p_{b t}=0\). c. Is it also true here that \(\partial c / \partial p_{b}\) and \(\partial c / \partial p_{t}\) are equal to \(0 ?\)

Hard Times Burt buys only rotgut whiskey and jelly donuts to sustain him. For Burt, rotgut whiskey is an inferior good that exhibits Giffen's paradox, although rotgut whiskey and jelly donuts are Hicksian substitutes in the customary sense. Develop an intuitive explanation to suggest why an increase in the price of rotgut whiskey must cause fewer jelly donuts to be bought. That is, the goods must also be gross complements.

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free