Suppose that the production of crayons \((q)\) is conducted at two locations and uses only labor as an input. The production function in location 1 is given by \(q_{1}=10 l_{1}^{0.5}\) and in location 2 by \(q_{2}=50 l_{2}^{0.5}\) a. If a single firm produces crayons in both locations, then it will obviously want to get as large an output as possible given the labor input it uses. How should it allocate labor between the locations to do so? Explain precisely the relationship between \(l_{1}\) and \(l_{2}\) b. Assuming that the firm operates in the efficient manner described in part (a), how does total output ( \(q\) ) depend on the total amount of labor hired \((l) ?\)

Short Answer

Expert verified
Answer: The firm should allocate labor in such a way that for every unit of labor employed at location 2, they should employ 5 units of labor at location 1. The total output as a function of the total labor hired is given by \(q(l) = 10 (5 \frac{l}{6})^{0.5} + 50 (\frac{l}{6})^{0.5}\).

Step by step solution

01

Calculate the Marginal Product of Labor at Each Location

First, we'll calculate the marginal product of labor (MPL) for both locations. The MPL is the additional amount of output produced when an extra unit of labor is employed. To find the MPL for each location, we'll differentiate the production functions with respect to the labor input: For location 1: MPL\(_{1} = \frac{d(q_{1})}{d(l_{1})} = \frac{d(10 l_{1}^{0.5})}{d(l_{1})} = 5 l_{1}^{-0.5}\) For location 2: MPL\(_{2} = \frac{d(q_{2})}{d(l_{2})} = \frac{d(50 l_{2}^{0.5})}{d(l_{2})} = 25 l_{2}^{-0.5}\)
02

Equate Marginal Products to Find the Relationship Between \(l_{1}\) and \(l_{2}\)

To maximize output, the firm should allocate labor between the two locations in such a way that the marginal products are equal. This ensures that the last unit of labor employed in each location produces the same amount of output. Equating the marginal products: \(5 l_{1}^{-0.5} = 25 l_{2}^{-0.5}\) To express the relationship between \(l_{1}\) and \(l_{2}\), we will isolate one of the variables: \(l_{1} = 5 l_{2}\) This relationship shows that the firm should allocate 5 times more labor to location 1 than location 2 to maximize output.
03

Express Total Output as a Function of Total Labor Hired

Now, we need to express the total output (q) as a function of the total amount of labor hired (l). To do this, first, combine the production function of both locations: \(q = q_{1} + q_{2} = 10 l_{1}^{0.5} + 50 l_{2}^{0.5}\) Next, we can use the relationship between \(l_{1}\) and \(l_{2}\) from step 2: \(l_{1} = 5 l_{2}\) Now, express \(l_{1}\) as a function of \(l_{2}\): \(l_{1}^{0.5} = (5 l_{2})^{0.5}\) Substitute this back into the total output function: \(q = 10 (5 l_{2})^{0.5} + 50 l_{2}^{0.5}\) Finally, notice that total labor hired is given by \(l = l_{1} + l_{2}\). To express total output (q) as a function of total labor hired (l), use the relationship we found earlier between \(l_{1}\) and \(l_{2}\) and the fact that \(l_{1} = 5 l_{2}\): \(l = 5 l_{2} + l_{2}\). Therefore, \(l_{2} = \frac{l}{6}\). Substitute this back into the total output function: \(q = 10 (5 \frac{l}{6})^{0.5} + 50 (\frac{l}{6})^{0.5}\) Now we have the total output as a function of the total amount of labor hired: \(q(l) = 10 (5 \frac{l}{6})^{0.5} + 50 (\frac{l}{6})^{0.5}\)

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Production Function
The production function is a mathematical representation of the relationship between the inputs used in production and the resulting output. In our crayon manufacturing example, we have two distinct production functions for two locations, expressed as location 1: \(q_{1} = 10 l_{1}^{0.5}\) and location 2: \(q_{2} = 50 l_{2}^{0.5}\). These functions indicate that the output of crayons at each location is dependent on the amount of labor allocated, with labor being the only input in this case.

To comprehend the production function further, let's break down the elements:\(q_{1}\) and \(q_{2}\) represent the quantity of crayons produced in location 1 and location 2, respectively. The input, labor, is shown by \(l_{1}\) and \(l_{2}\), and is raised to the power of 0.5, signifying a square root relationship between labor input and output. This power indicates diminishing marginal returns, a common concept in economics where each additional unit of input produces less additional output. The production function's coefficients (10 for location 1 and 50 for location 2) help to quantify the efficiency of each location in transforming labor into crayons.
Labor Allocation Optimization
Optimizing labor allocation is crucial for firms aiming to maximize their output. In our scenario, the company needs to distribute labor between two locations to optimize production of crayons. The solution entails equating the Marginal Product of Labor (MPL) for each location, which represents the incremental output achieved by employing an additional unit of labor. Mathematically, it is the derivative of the production function regarding labor.

The step by step solution provided uses calculus to find the MPL for both locations, leading to the relationship \(5 l_{1}^{-0.5} = 25 l_{2}^{-0.5}\). By isolating the variables, we can reveal that \(l_{1} = 5 l_{2}\), suggesting that for every unit of labor assigned to location 2, five units should be assigned to location 1 to achieve optimal output. This strategic resource allocation is vital for businesses that want to utilize their labor force effectively and is an exemplary application of marginal analysis in the decision-making process.
Total Output as a Function of Labor
Understanding how total output varies with the amount of labor hired is fundamental in managerial decision-making. With our firm's production situation, total output \(q\) is the sum of outputs from both locations. To derive a single equation for total output as a function of total labor hired \(l\), we combined the individual production functions and utilized the established relationship between \(l_{1}\) and \(l_{2}\).

After some algebraic manipulation, as shown in the solution, we arrived at the total output function \(q(l) = 10 (5 \frac{l}{6})^{0.5} + 50 (\frac{l}{6})^{0.5}\). This function allows the firm to determine the expected total output of crayons for any given level of total labor hired. It consolidates the production capabilities of both locations into a single perspective, empowering the firm to forecast production and make informed labor hiring decisions according to their operational requirements and market demands.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Although much of our discussion of measuring the elasticity of substitution for various production functions has assumed constant returns to scale, often that assumption is not necessary. This problem illustrates some of these cases. a. In footnote 6 we pointed out that, in the constant returns-to-scale case, the elasticity of substitution for a two-input production function is given by $$\sigma=\frac{f_{k} f_{l}}{f \cdot f_{k l}}$$ Suppose now that we define the homothetic production function \(F\) as $$F(k, l)=[f(k, l)]^{\gamma}$$ where \(f(k, l)\) is a constant returns-to-scale production function and \(\gamma\) is a positive exponent. Show that the elasticity of substitution for this production function is the same as the elasticity of substitution for the function \(f\) b. Show how this result can be applied to both the Cobb-Douglas and CES production functions.

Power Goat Lawn Company uses two sizes of mowers to cut lawns. The smaller mowers have a 22 -inch deck. The larger ones combine two of the 22 -inch decks in a single mower. For each size of mower, Power Goat has a different production function, given by the rows of the following table. $$\begin{array}{lccc} \hline & \begin{array}{c} \text { Output per Hour } \\ \text { (square feet) } \end{array} & \begin{array}{c} \text { Capital Input } \\ \text { (# of 22" mowers) } \end{array} & \text { Labor Input } \\ \hline \text { Small mowers } & 5000 & 1 & 1 \\ \text { Large mowers } & 8000 & 2 & 1 \\ \hline \end{array}$$ a. Graph the \(q=40,000\) square feet isoquant for the first production function. How much \(k\) and \(l\) would be used if these factors were combined without waste? b. Answer part (a) for the second function. c. How much \(k\) and \(l\) would be used without waste if half of the 40,000 -square-foot lawn were cut by the method of the first production function and half by the method of the second? How much \(k\) and \(l\) would be used if one fourth of the lawn were cut by the first method and three fourths by the second? What does it mean to speak of fractions of \(k\) and \(l\) ? d. Based on your observations in part (c), draw a \(q=40,000\) isoquant for the combined production functions.

A local measure of the returns to scale incorporated in a production function is given by the scale elasticity \(e_{q, t}=\partial f(t k, t l) / \partial t \cdot t / q\) evaluated at \(t=1\) a. Show that if the production function exhibits constant returns to scale, then \(e_{q, t}=1\) b. We can define the output elasticities of the inputs \(k\) and \(l\) as $$\begin{array}{l} e_{q, k}=\frac{\partial f(k, l)}{\partial k} \cdot \frac{k}{q} \\ e_{q, l}=\frac{\partial f(k, l)}{\partial l} \cdot \frac{l}{q} \end{array}$$ Show that \(e_{q, t}=e_{q, k}+e_{q, l}\) c. A function that exhibits variable scale elasticity is $$q=\left(1+k^{-1} l^{-1}\right)^{-1}$$ Show that, for this function, \(e_{q, t}>1\) for \(q<0.5\) and that \(e_{q, t}<1\) for \(q>0.5\) d. Explain your results from part (c) intuitively. Hint: Does \(q\) have an upper bound for this production function?

Suppose the production function for widgets is given by $$q=k l-0.8 k^{2}-0.2 l^{2}$$ where \(q\) represents the annual quantity of widgets produced, \(k\) represents annual capital input, and \(l\) represents annual labor input. a. Suppose \(k=10 ;\) graph the total and average productivity of labor curves. At what level of labor input does this average productivity reach a maximum? How many widgets are produced at that point? b. Again assuming that \(k=10\), graph the \(M P_{l}\) curve. At what level of labor input does \(M P_{l}=0\) ? c. Suppose capital inputs were increased to \(k=20 .\) How would your answers to parts (a) and (b) change? d. Does the widget production function exhibit constant, increasing, or decreasing returns to scale?

As we have seen in many places, the general Cobb-Douglas production function for two inputs is given by $$q=f(k, l)=A k^{\alpha} l^{\beta}$$ where \(0<\alpha<1\) and \(0<\beta<1 .\) For this production function: a. Show that \(f_{k}>0, f_{1}>0, f_{k k}<0, f_{l l}<0,\) and \(f_{k l}=f_{l k}>0\) b. Show that \(e_{q, k}=\alpha\) and \(e_{q, l}=\beta\) c. In footnote \(5,\) we defined the scale elasticity as$$e_{q, t}=\frac{\partial f(t k, t l)}{\partial t} \cdot \frac{t}{f(t k, t l)}$$ where the expression is to be evaluated at \(t=1 .\) Show that, for this Cobb-Douglas function, \(e_{q, t}=\alpha+\beta .\) Hence in this case the scale elasticity and the returns to scale of the production function agree (for more on this concept see Problem 9.9 ). d. Show that this function is quasi-concave. e. Show that the function is concave for \(\alpha+\beta \leq 1\) but not concave for \(\alpha+\beta>1\)

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free