Ms. Sarah Traveler does not own a car and travels only by bus, train, or plane. Her utility function is given by $$\text { utility }=\boldsymbol{B}-\boldsymbol{T}^{\prime} \boldsymbol{P}$$ where each letter stands for miles traveled by a specific mode. Suppose that the ratio of the price of train travel to that of bus travel \(\left(P, / P_{B}\right)\) never changes. a. How might one define a composite commodity for ground transportation? b. Phrase Sarah's optimization problem as one of choosing between ground (G) and air (P) transportation. c. What are Sarah's demand functions for Gand P? d. Once Sarah decides how much to spend on \(G\), how will she allocate those expenditures between \(B\) and \(7 ?\)

Short Answer

Expert verified
Answer: The demand functions for ground (G) and air (P) transportation are: - Ground (G) Demand Function: $$G = P_G K_G = K_G$$, where \(K_G\) is the constant of proportionality. - Air (P) Demand Function: $$P^{'} = \frac{1}{P_P} K_P = K_P$$, where \(K_P\) is the constant of proportionality.

Step by step solution

01

Define Composite Commodity for Ground Transportation

A composite commodity for ground transportation can be defined by combining the Bus and Train modes of travel, since they both belong to the same category of ground transportation. Let G represent the composite commodity for ground transportation, then G = B + T.
02

Phrase Sarah's Optimization Problem

Sarah's optimization problem can be rephrased as choosing between ground (G) and air (P) transportation. Thus, her utility function can be represented as: $$\text{utility} = G - P^{'} P$$
03

Derive Demand Functions for G and P

To derive the demand functions for G and P, we need to find the marginal utility of each mode of transportation with respect to the price of the transportation. The marginal utility of G is: $$\frac{\partial (\text{utility})}{\partial G} = 1$$ The marginal utility of P is: $$\frac{\partial (\text{utility})}{\partial P} = -P^{'}$$ Now, we can find the demand functions for G and P by setting the marginal utility equal to their respective prices (denoted as \(P_G\) and \(P_P\)) and then solve for G and P. For G: $$1 = P_G$$ So, $$G = P_G K_G = K_G$$, where \(K_G\) is the constant of proportionality. For P: $$-P^{'} = P_P$$ So, $$P^{'} = \frac{1}{P_P} K_P = K_P$$, where \(K_P\) is the constant of proportionality.
04

Allocate Expenditures between B and T

Once Sarah decides how much to spend on G, she will allocate her expenditures between B and T based on the given price ratio, \(P(P_T / P_B)\). Since the price ratio never changes, Sarah will allocate her expenditures between B and T according to the same proportion. Let \(x\) be the proportion spent on Bus (B) and \(1-x\) be the proportion spent on Train (T). Then, the allocation of expenditures can be represented as: $$B = x(P_G K_G)$$ $$T = (1 - x)(P_G K_G)$$ In conclusion, by analyzing the given utility function, we defined a composite commodity for ground transportation, rephrased Sarah's optimization problem, derived the demand functions for ground and air transportation, and determined how she will allocate her expenditures between Bus and Train travel.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

Suppose that an individual consumes three goods, \(X_{u} X_{2},\) and \(X_{3},\) and that \(X_{2}\) and \(X_{3}\) are similar commodities (i.e., cheap and expensive restaurant meals) with \(P_{2}=\mathrm{KP}_{3}\) where \(K<1-\) that is, the goods' prices have a constant relationship to one another. a. Show that \(\mathrm{X}_{2}\) and \(\mathrm{X}_{3}\) can be treated as a composite commodity. b. Suppose both \(\mathrm{X}_{2}\) and \(\mathrm{X}_{3}\) are subject to a transaction cost of \(t\) per unit (for some exam ples, see Problem 6.6 ). How will this transaction cost affect the price of \(X_{2}\) relative to that of \(\mathrm{X}_{3} ?\) How will this effect vary with the value of \(t ?\) c. Can you predict how an income-compensated increase in \(t\) will affect expenditures on the composite commodity \(\mathrm{X}_{2}\) and \(\mathrm{X}_{3} ?\) Does the composite commodity theorem strictly apply to this case? d. How will an income-compensated increase in \(t\) affect how total spending on the com posite commodity is allocated between \(X_{2}\) and \(X_{3} ?\) (For a further discussion of the complications involved in this problem, see \(T . E\) Borcherding and E. Silberberg, "Shipping the Good Apples Out: The Alchian- Allen Theorem Reconsidered," Journal ofPolitical Economy [February 1978]: 131-138.)

A utility function is termed separable if it can be written as \\[\left.U(X, Y)=U^{\wedge} X\right)+U_{2}(Y)\\] where \(U \backslash>0, U^{\prime \prime}<0,\) and \(U_{u} U_{2}\) need not be the same function. a. What does separability assume about the cross partial derivative \(U_{X Y} ?\) Give an intuitive discussion of what word this condition means and in what situations it might be plausible. b. Show that if utility is separable, neither good can be inferior. c. Does the assumption of separability allow you to conclude definitively whether \(X\) and \(Y\) are gross substitutes or gross complements? Explain. d. Use the Cobb-Douglas utility function to show that separability is not invariant with respect to monotonic transformations. Note: Separable functions are examined in more detail in the Extensions to this chapter.

Hard Times Burt buys only rotgut whiskey and jelly donuts to sustain him. For Burt, rotgut whiskey is an inferior good that exhibits Giffen's paradox, although rotgut whiskey and jelly donuts are Hicksian substitutes in the customary sense. Develop an intuitive explanation to suggest why a rise in the price of rotgut must cause fewer jelly donuts to be bought. That is, the goods must also be gross complements.

Hicks's "second law" of demand states that the predominant relationship among goods is net substitutability (see footnote 3 of Chapter 6 ). To prove this result: a. Show why compensated demand functions $$X ;=h,\left(P_{U} \ldots, P_{n}, V\right)$$ are homogeneous of degree zero in \(P_{x} \ldots P_{n}\) for a given level of \(V\) b. Use Euler's theorem for homogeneous functions (for a statement of this theorem, see footnote 5 of Chapter 7 ) to show that \(=0 \text { (for all } i=1, n)\) c. Use the "first law of demand" to conclude that is, net substitution must prevail, on average.

Example 6.3 computes the demand functions implied by the three-good CES utility function a. Use the demand function for Xin Equation 6.28 to determine whether Xand For Xand Z are gross substitutes or gross complements. b. How would you determine whether \(X\) and \(Y\) or \(X\) and \(Z\) are net substitutes or net complements?

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free