Ms. Sarah Traveler does not own a car and travels only by bus, train, or plane. Her utility function is given by utility \(=B \cdot T \cdot P\) where each letter stands for miles traveled by a specific mode. Suppose that the ratio of the price of train travel to that of bus travel \(\left(P_{T} / P_{B}\right)\) never changes. a. How might one define a composite commodity for ground transportation? b. Phrase Sarah's optimization problem as one of choosing between ground ( \(G\) ) and air \((P)\) transportation c. What are Sarah's demand functions for \(G\) and \(P\) ? d. Once Sarah decides how much to spend on \(G\), how will she allocate those expenditures between \(B\) and \(T ?\)

Short Answer

Expert verified
Answer: Sarah allocates her ground transportation expenditures between bus and train travel based on the fixed price ratio between the two. She spends a proportion of 1/(1+k) of her total expenditure on ground transportation on bus travel, and a proportion of k/(1+k) of her total expenditure on ground transportation on train travel, where k is the constant representing the fixed price ratio between train and bus travel.

Step by step solution

01

Part a: Define a composite commodity for ground transportation

To define a composite commodity for ground transportation, we will combine bus \((B)\) and train \((T)\) travel into a single good \((G)\). Since the price ratio of train travel to bus travel \( \left( \frac{P_{T}}{P_{B}} \right) \) never changes, we can represent this composite commodity in terms of one of the individual grounds of transportation, say bus \((B)\). Then, the composite commodity for ground transportation can be defined as \(G = kB\) where \(k\) is a constant representing the fixed price ratio between train and bus travel.
02

Part b: Optimization problem

Sarah's optimization problem can be rephrased as one of choosing between the ground (\(G\)) and air (\(P\)) transportation. Given her utility function, \(U = B \cdot T \cdot P\), we can now rewrite it using the composite commodity as \(U = \frac{G}{k} \cdot kT \cdot P\). The optimization problem is to maximize her utility function given her budget constraint, which can be written as \(P_{G} G + P_{P} P \leq I\) where \(P_{G}\) is the price of ground transportation, \(P_{P}\) is the price of air transportation, and \(I\) is her income.
03

Part c: Demand functions for \(G\) and \(P\)

To find Sarah's demand functions for \(G\) and \(P\), we need to solve her optimization problem. We can use the Lagrange multiplier method to find the optimal values of \(G\) and \(P\). The Lagrangian function is $$\mathcal{L}(G, P, \lambda) = \frac{G}{k} \cdot kT \cdot P + \lambda (I - P_{G} G - P_{P} P).$$ Taking the partial derivatives with respect to \(G\), \(P\), and \(\lambda\), we have: $$\frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial G} = \frac{1}{k} \cdot kT \cdot P - \lambda P_{G} = 0$$ $$\frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial P} = \frac{G}{k} \cdot kT - \lambda P_{P} = 0$$ $$\frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial \lambda} = I - P_{G} G - P_{P} P = 0$$ Solve this system of equations to obtain the optimal values of \(G\) and \(P\), which will represent Sarah's demand functions for ground \((G)\) and air \((P)\) transportation.
04

Part d: Allocate expenditures between \(B\) and \(T\)

Once Sarah decides how much to spend on ground transportation (\(G\)), she will allocate her expenditures between bus \((B)\) and train \((T)\) travel based on the fixed price ratio, as given. Since the composite commodity is defined as \(G = kB\), where \(k = \frac{P_{T}}{P_{B}}\), she will spend \(k\) times more on train travel than on bus travel. That is: $$Expenditure_{T} = k \cdot Expenditure_{B}$$ So, the proportion of her ground transportation expenditures allocated to bus travel will be \(\frac{1}{(1+k)}\) of the total expenditure on \(G\), and the proportion allocated to train travel will be \(\frac{k}{(1+k)}\) of the total expenditure on \(G\).

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

In general, uncompensated cross-price effects are not equal. That is, $$\frac{\partial X_{i}}{\partial P_{j}} \neq \frac{\partial X_{j}}{\partial P_{i}}$$ Use the generalized Slutsky equation to show that these effects are equal if the individual spends a constant fraction of income on each good regardless of relative prices. (This is a generalization of Problem 6.1

A utility function is termed separable if it can be written as $$U(X, Y)=U_{1}(X)+U_{2}(Y),$$ where \(U_{i}^{\prime}>0, U_{i}^{\prime \prime}<0,\) and \(U_{1}, U_{2}\) need not be the same function. a. What does separability assume about the cross partial derivative \(U_{X Y} ?\) Give an intuitive discussion of what word this condition means and in what situations it might be plausible. b. Show that if utility is separable, neither good can be inferior. c. Does the assumption of separability allow you to conclude definitively whether \(X\) and \(Y\) are gross substitutes or gross complements? Explain. d. Use the Cobb-Douglas utility function to show that separability is not invariant with respect to monotonic transformations. Note: Separable functions are examined in more detail in the Extensions to this chapter.

Heidi receives utility from two goods, goat's milk ( \(M\) ) and strudel (S), according to the utility function $$U(M, S)=M \cdot S$$ a. Show that increases in the price of goat's milk will not affect the quantity of strudel Heidi buys - that is, show that \(\partial S / \partial P_{M}=0\) b. Show also that \(\partial M / \partial P_{s}=0\) c. Use the Slutsky equation and the symmetry of net substitution effects to prove that the income effects involved with the derivatives in parts a and b are identical. d. Prove part c explicitly using the Marshallian demand functions for \(M\) and \(S\).

Hicks's "second law" of demand states that the predominant relationship among goods is net substitutability (see footnote 3 of Chapter 6 ). To prove this result: a. Show why compensated demand functions $$X_{i}=h_{i}\left(P_{1}, \ldots, P_{n}, V\right)$$ are homogeneous of degree zero in \(P_{1} \ldots P_{n}\) for a given level of \(V\) b. Use Euler's theorem for homogeneous functions (for a statement of this theorem, see footnote 5 of Chapter 7 ) to show that $$\left.\left.\sum_{j=1}^{n} P_{j} \frac{\partial X_{i}}{\partial P_{j}}\right|_{U=\text { constant }}=0 \text { (for all } i=1, n\right)$$ c. Use the "first law of demand" $$\left(\text { that }\left.\frac{\partial X_{i}}{\partial P_{i}}\right|_{U=\text { constant }} \leq 0\right)$$ to conclude that $$\left.\sum_{j \neq 1} P_{j} \frac{\partial X_{i}}{\partial P_{j}}\right|_{U=\mathrm{constant}} \geq 0$$ that is, net substitution must prevail, on average.

Hard Times Burt buys only rotgut whiskey and jelly donuts to sustain him. For Burt, rotgut whiskey is an inferior good that exhibits Giffen's paradox, although rotgut whiskey and jelly donuts are Hicksian substitutes in the customary sense. Develop an intuitive explanation to suggest why a rise in the price of rotgut must cause fewer jelly donuts to be bought. That is, the goods must also be gross complements.

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free