Julio receives utility from consuming food ( \(F\) ) and clothing \((C)\) as given by the utility function \(U(F, C)=F C\) In addition, the price of food is \(\$ 2\) per unit, the price of clothing is \(\$ 10\) per unit, and Julio's weekly income is \$50. a. What is Julio's marginal rate of substitution of food for clothing when utility is maximized? Explain. b. Suppose instead that Julio is consuming a bundle with more food and less clothing than his utility maximizing bundle. Would his marginal rate of substitution of food for clothing be greater than or less than your answer in part a? Explain.

Short Answer

Expert verified
a. The MRS when utility is maximized will be calculated based on the given utility function and budget constraint. b. If Julio consumes more food and less clothing than his utility-maximizing bundle, his Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS) of food for clothing will be less than the answer in part a.

Step by step solution

01

Set up the budget constraint

Start by setting up the budget constraint which will be \(2F + 10C = 50\). It represents all combinations of food and clothing Julio could purchase with his given income.
02

Calculation of the marginal utilities

Next, based on the utility function \(U=F * C\), calculate the marginal utility for each good. The marginal utility can be obtained by differentiating the utility function with respect to each good. The marginal utility of food, \(MU_F\), is \(C\) (the derivative of \(F*C\) with respect to \(F\)). Similarly, the marginal utility of clothing, \(MU_C\), is \(F\) (the derivative of \(F*C\) with respect to \(C\)).
03

Calculating the MRS

The MRS at the point \(F^*,C^*\), where utility is maximized, is given by \(MU_F / MU_C\). Thus, the MRS here is \(C / F\). Now optimize this considering the budget constraint.
04

Optimize the utility

Use the condition for utility maximization, that is, \(MU_F/P_F = MU_C/P_C\). Substituting \(MU_F, MU_C, P_F, P_C\) we get \(C/2 = F/10\). By resolving this equation and substitizing it into the budget constraint we find optimal quantities for F and C, which can then be plugged back into our MRS expression.
05

Analyze a different consumption bundle

In the final step, analyze a bundle with more food and less clothing than the utility-maximizing bundle. Since the utility function is Cobb–Douglas, the MRS of food for clothing is decreasing in the amount of food consumed. Therefore, if Julio consumes more food than in his utility-maximizing bundle, his MRS of food for clothing will be smaller than in part a.

Unlock Step-by-Step Solutions & Ace Your Exams!

  • Full Textbook Solutions

    Get detailed explanations and key concepts

  • Unlimited Al creation

    Al flashcards, explanations, exams and more...

  • Ads-free access

    To over 500 millions flashcards

  • Money-back guarantee

    We refund you if you fail your exam.

Over 30 million students worldwide already upgrade their learning with Vaia!

Key Concepts

These are the key concepts you need to understand to accurately answer the question.

Utility Maximization
Utility maximization is a fundamental concept in microeconomics, referring to the behavior of consumers aiming to get the highest level of satisfaction or 'utility' from their consumption choices within the limits of their budget. When consumers make decisions about how to spend their money, they typically try to choose the combination of goods and services that will maximize their happiness or satisfaction.

To quantify this intuitive idea, economists use mathematical functions called 'utility functions' which represent preferences for combinations of different goods. Consumers reach utility maximization when they cannot increase their utility by changing the consumption bundle, given their budget. This state is found where the consumer's budget constraint is tangent to an indifference curve, representing the trade-offs a consumer is willing to make between two goods. In other words, the point where the consumer has balanced the marginal utility per dollar spent across all goods.
Budget Constraint
The budget constraint in economics outlines the combinations of goods and services a consumer can purchase with a given income at specific prices. It serves as a boundary that limits a consumer's consumption choices. Represented graphically, the budget line is downward sloping, indicating that if a consumer spends more on one good, they must spend less on another to stay within their budget.

Formally, if a consumer has an income 'I,' and the prices of two goods are 'P1' and 'P2,' the budget constraint is given by the equation 'P1X1 + P2X2 = I', where 'X1' and 'X2' represent quantities of the two goods. The slope of the budget line reflects the trade-offs and is determined by the price ratio of the two goods. The consumer’s goal is to find the highest utility they can achieve without crossing this budget line.
Marginal Utility
Marginal utility is the additional satisfaction or utility that a consumer receives from consuming one more unit of a good or service. It can be thought of as the 'extra value' a consumer gets from an additional unit. In economic theory, as one consumes more units of a good, the marginal utility of additional units typically decreases—a phenomenon known as the law of diminishing marginal utility.

Mathematically, marginal utility is the derivative of the utility function with respect to the quantity of the good consumed. In the context of the problem, where the utility function is given by 'U(F, C) = F * C', the marginal utility of food, 'MU_F', is the derivative of the utility function with respect to 'F', which is 'C'. Similarly, the marginal utility of clothing, 'MU_C', is the derivative with respect to 'C', which is 'F'. Consumers maximize utility by equating the ratio of marginal utilities of two goods to the ratio of their prices.
Cobb-Douglas Utility Function
The Cobb-Douglas utility function is a specific type of utility function widely used in economics to represent consumer preferences. It takes the form 'U(X, Y) = X^a * Y^b', where 'X' and 'Y' are the quantities of two different goods consumed, and 'a' and 'b' are parameters that reflect the relative importance of each good for the consumer.

The function implies that the goods are perfect substitutes to some degree and that the marginal rate of substitution is diminishing. This property means that as a consumer has more of 'X' and less of 'Y', they are willing to give up less of 'X' for an additional unit of 'Y'. It also results in indifference curves that are convex to the origin, which shows the trade-off between 'X' and 'Y' at different levels of utility. The Cobb-Douglas form allows for constant returns to scale; if the quantities of all goods are multiplied by a common factor, total utility is multiplied by the same factor.

One App. One Place for Learning.

All the tools & learning materials you need for study success - in one app.

Get started for free

Most popular questions from this chapter

In this chapter, consumer preferences for various commodities did not change during the analysis. In some situations, however, preferences do change as consumption occurs. Discuss why and how preferences might change over time with consumption of these two commodities: a. cigarettes. b. dinner for the first time at a restaurant with a special cuisine.

Connie has a monthly income of \(\$ 200\) that she allocates between two goods: meat and potatoes. a. Suppose meat costs \(\$ 4\) per pound and potatoes \(\$ 2\) per pound. Draw her budget constraint. b. Suppose also that her utility function is given by the equation \(U(M, P)=2 M+P .\) What combination of meat and potatoes should she buy to maximize her utility? (Hint: Meat and potatoes are perfect substitutes.) c. Connie's supermarket has a special promotion. If she buys 20 pounds of potatoes (at \(\$ 2\) per pound), she gets the next 10 pounds for free. This offer applies only to the first 20 pounds she buys. All potatoes in excess of the first 20 pounds (excluding bonus potatoes are still \(\$ 2\) per pound. Draw her budget constraint. d. An outbreak of potato rot raises the price of potatoes to \(\$ 4\) per pound. The supermarket ends its promotion. What does her budget constraint look like now? What combination of meat and potatoes maximizes her utility?

The utility that Meredith receives by consuming food \(F\) and clothing \(C\) is given by \(U(F, C)=F C .\) Suppose that Meredith's income in 1990 is \(\$ 1200\) and that the prices of food and clothing are \(\$ 1\) per unit for each. By 2000 however, the price of food has increased to \(\$ 2\) and the price of clothing to \(\$ 3 .\) Let 100 represent the cost of living index for \(1990 .\) Calculate the ideal and the Laspeyres cost-of-living index for Meredith for 2000 (Hint: Meredith will spend equal amounts on food and clothing with these preferences.)

Connie has a monthly income of \(\$ 200\) that she allocates between two goods: meat and potatoes. a. Suppose meat costs \(\$ 4\) per pound and potatoes \(\$ 2\) per pound. Draw her budget constraint. b. Suppose also that her utility function is given by the equation \(U(M, P)=2 M+P .\) What combination of meat and potatoes should she buy to maximize her utility? (Hint: Meat and potatoes are perfect substitutes.) c. Connie's supermarket has a special promotion. If she buys 20 pounds of potatoes (at \(\$ 2\) per pound), she gets the next 10 pounds for free. This offer applies only to the first 20 pounds she buys. All potatoes in excess of the first 20 pounds (excluding bonus potatoes are still \(\$ 2\) per pound. Draw her budget constraint. d. An outbreak of potato rot raises the price of potatoes to \(\$ 4\) per pound. The supermarket ends its promotion. What does her budget constraint look like now? What combination of meat and potatoes maximizes her utility?

Debra usually buys a soft drink when she goes to a movie theater, where she has a choice of three sizes: the 8 -ounce drink costs \(\$ 1.50\), the 12 -ounce drink \(\$ 2.00\) and the 16 -ounce drink \(\$ 2.25 .\) Describe the budget constraint that Debra faces when deciding how many ounces of the drink to purchase. (Assume that Debra can costlessly dispose of any of the soft drink that she does not want.

See all solutions

What do you think about this solution?

We value your feedback to improve our textbook solutions.

Study anywhere. Anytime. Across all devices.

Sign-up for free